The exit of Cogentrix from Karnataka.
Desmond Fernandes and
Leo Saldanha Citation: Fernandes D and Saldanha L, 'Deep Politics, Liberalisation and Corruption: The Mangalore Power Corporation Controversy', 2000(1) Law, Social Justice and Global Development (LGD).
Click here for the original paper, published on Jan 10, 2001
The avowed need for liberalisation, specifically in the Indian power
sector, is analysed in an elaborate manner by examining the economic
aspects of generation, transmission and distribution of power in
India, prior to and post liberalisation. Drawing upon the experiences
with Enron, the case of Cogentrix is followed from the time of its
arrival in India, the many highs and lows in the struggle against
the project, the casualties to the project, through to its hard fought
exit.
The political and legal detail in terms of events, procedures, arguments
in and outside of court are meant to emphasise the notion of deep politics.
By pitting the ideology of liberalisation against the political systems in
India, notions of good governance are examined to suggest that deep
politics is the current reality.
February 2001
[Published with the permission of Leo Saldanha of the Environment
Support Group, Bangalore]
Excerpts from the paper
...Bhupal Singh has concluded that the reform [liberalization] agenda
has failed to achieve the stated aims. The 40 Private Sector projects
awarded through the competitive bidding route, (and) 100 projects through
the negotiated route, were expected to create an additional capacity of
20,000 MW with attract investment of Rs. 65,000 crores. However in reality
construction has started only on about 3,500 MW additional capacity in
the private sector (Singh, 1997). The counter-guarantee had been given by
the Government of India (favouring) fast track projects initially, since
according to the credit rating of the country was supposed to be quite low.
The fact (however) is that a number of foreign countries with advanced power
technology were willing to back up their country's equipment manufacturers
initially to promote the sale of equipment to India despite its so called
poor credit rating. However, personal visits abroad by vested interests
(individuals who were in positions of power) during the liberalisation phase
made foreign companies more aggressive and assertive putting (India) on
the defensive. Therefore a disadvantageous scenario (has) emerged (resulting in)
most of the fast-track projects (coming up) through negotiations rather than
through competitive bidding. The likely (adverse) impact of forex commitments
of allowing repatriation of profits (due to) sovereign counter guarantees
on India's meagre financial resources struck the formulators of this policy
quite late[6].
Further most of the private power projects have been dragging
as the proposals have run into controversy that have led to delays mainly
because of lack of transparency. Unforeseen hurdles have been encountered
because either experts were not consulted in advance (and/or) people with
flimsy knowledge (were placed in high positions and) were made to append
their signatures here and there with a view to offload the responsibility
of the bureaucracy and politicians (Singh, 1997).
V Ranganathan, Professor of Economics at the Indian Institute of
Management (IIM), Bangalore, has also detailed the way in which these reforms
in power sector in India are being driven by a shortage of Government finance.
He contends that to a large extent, the reforms driven through external
influence. These external influences can take the form of conditionalities
attached to institutional and other funding and consequently force-fed.
One consequence of this has been the blurring of the distinction between
ends and means; privatisation which should be regarded as a means to achieve
the end of competition, is in our context resorted to as an end in itself,
resulting in a public monopoly being replaced by a private monopoly.
Further it needs to be understood, that privatisation alone without scope
for competition, need not deliver improved results. However, regrettably,
even in areas such as generation where competition is possible, we have
not attempted the right steps. We assure a guaranteed load, and a guaranteed
return for each specific location and for each specific fuel, thereby
protecting inefficiency and providing super-normal profits to the private IPP.
From the process of reform it can be inferred that there is a certain
lack of confidence in the reform process even in the bureaucracy itself.
At best, it is done, as a means to get World Bank or ADB (Asian Development Bank)
loans, because, like Charlamagne who commandeered 'Baptism or total annihilation',
these organisations say privatisation or no loans. This reticence and
inability to deal effectively with the various aspects of privatisation and
reforms in the worst case scenario can actually transfer the consumers' surplus
to the producer (Ranganathan, 1997).
|